Despite the differences between the US and Europe in the average
citizen’s experience of life, there have been some striking similarities in the
development of deeper structures in the world’s two biggest economies since the advent of neoliberalism. This
indicates that the crisis in Europe is not merely a result of “contamination”
from the American credit crisis of 2008, as many Europeans initially argued.
Yet neither is it a result of solely European problems of excessive spending or
lagging competitiveness, as many Germans and Americans believe. It is, rather,
a constituent part of the ongoing crisis of global neoliberalism.
It’s much harder to get a good grasp on these developments in Europe because aggregated statistics are not readily available before the advent of the eurozone and because exchange rates introduce some methodological problems, not to mention that the most important national economy used to be two different countries. This is further
complicated by the UK’s decision to stay out of the single currency, leaving
one of the key economies of Europe out of eurozone statistics. I’ve had no luck
finding continuous time series that could give us the kind of elegant graphical
picture of trends from Fordism to neoliberalism that we get for the US, so a
more impressionistic jumble of charts for individual countries will have to
suffice.
At least in France, this has been accomplished by the same kind of wage suppression as in the US. Here we see that wages rose with productivity in the Fordist period and diverged sharply with the advent of neoliberalism (I was unable to locate similar data for other countries stretching back far enough, though the rising share of value going to capital indicates that this is a common phenomenon throughout Europe):
and France (the blue line is debt as a percentage of GDP):
First, like the United States, growth in productivity has declined substantially from
the rapid increases of the Fordist era (these charts are based on data from
Eckhard Hein and Artur Tarassow, “Distribution, aggregate demand and
productivity growth: theory and empirical results for six OECD countries based
on a post-Kaleckian model”, Cambridge Journal of Economics (2010) 34, p.
728)
As can be seen, the collapse in productivity growth has been even
more marked than that in the US, though the American (and British) numbers are padded by the
tremendous amounts of fictitious capital its financial sector has generated since the mid-90s. As in the US, in order to maintain profit rates European
corporations have captured a rising share of society’s production of value since the neoliberal
rupture. The dotted lines below show the share of GDP taken by profits in A)
Germany, B) France, C) Netherlands, D) Austria, E) UK, F) US; the straight
lines show the evolution of productivity growth. Clearly, this development too
has been more striking in Europe than the US (from Hein and Tarassow, p. 746):
At least in France, this has been accomplished by the same kind of wage suppression as in the US. Here we see that wages rose with productivity in the Fordist period and diverged sharply with the advent of neoliberalism (I was unable to locate similar data for other countries stretching back far enough, though the rising share of value going to capital indicates that this is a common phenomenon throughout Europe):
Source |
Just as in the US, squeezing the enormous consumer market that had
emerged under Fordism produced two significant problems: the prospect
of mass unrest if living standards stagnated, and the question of how to
actually sell the economy’s growing output if consumers’ incomes were not rising.
And just as in the US, increasing levels of debt was the solution to both
problems. But – and this is the basis of many of the observed differences in
national life between the US and countries in Europe – the burden of this debt
was taken up primarily by governments in Europe while individual borrowers were more important in the
US (graph based on data supplied here):
In other words, broadly speaking, debt in Europe financed public
goods that were equitably distributed (healthcare, public transit, welfare programs) while in the US it financed McMansions and SUVs. But in both cases,
the issuance of this debt represented a claim on future production that could
not be made good because productive outlets for investment in the economy were
drying up.
We can see the sharp increase in government debts during the
neoliberal period here:
Source |
And, since that graph is a bit messy, here are individual ones for
Italy:
Source |
Source |
The rise of private debt in Europe, however, was also a significant development:
Finally, just as in the US, the financial sector as a whole has become more and more important in the European economy:
This graph overstates the significance of finance in the eurozone considered as a whole since French and German banks account for more of the sector than those of the other major economies, but the trend is clear. And with the exception of Greece and Italy, the speculative bubbles (mainly in real estate) that the European banks inflated in the UK, Spain, Ireland, and Iceland have been central to the seemingly national crises that have unfolded one after the other.
Source |
Source |
It goes without saying that there are many differences between the
US and Europe that complicate this basic picture considerably, and I hope that
we will have a chance to explore these further. But what I want to argue is that
in a very fundamental way, the two economies (and not just the economies, but
the politics and culture as well) have developed in a similar direction because
they both adopted neoliberal social forms in response to the crisis of the
1970s.
It can hardly be denied that the American version of neoliberal
social forms was far more extreme, marking a much sharper break with Fordist
social forms than in Europe (with the exception of the UK). The partial
survival of Fordist forms in Europe, including stronger unions, a more robust
sense of the public good, and a less complete exposure of people to market
insecurity, goes a long way toward explaining why life in Europe has been so
much less savage there over the last three decades. It also accounts for Europe’s
consistently slower rate of growth. These social forms were well adapted to the
Fordist moment, but they were less successful – at least in capitalist terms – under
neoliberal conditions.
Even so, precisely because neoliberalism was implemented in an
extreme fashion in the US, the dysfunctions of the system were most pronounced
there, and it was there that the crisis of neoliberalism exploded. Yet Europe,
as a part of the unitary global order of neoliberalism, was not immune. And because its underlying model of growth was the same as in the US –
consistent investment levels maintained only through corporations taking a rising share of
value, with the problem of realizing value being
solved through increasing debt – the crisis paralyzed prospects for
future growth.
This crisis of growth has now assumed the form of a crisis in government finances because of the peculiar monetary system that mediates the
euro. But the basic economic structures of neoliberalism remain in place, and
the ideologies generated by the neoliberal era continue to block any initiatives
but those that will deepen the crisis. It’s too soon to tell
if the crisis in Europe will finally undo the short-term fixes that have
forestalled complete global economic collapse. But even if the German
government and ECB finally decide to save the currency before it’s too late,
the crisis of growth will continue.
This is very helpful. I'd like to see you go further on the idea that the continental model of neoliberalism relied on sovereign debt as opposed to consumer debt. I wonder if there's a way to quantify consumption in such a way to show more clearly that the increase in debt was causally linked to lagging demand. You might be able to use import/export numbers combined with gross output numbers to quantify consumption to show an increase in or at least constant aggregate consumption while the proportion of spending moved toward debt or away from individual consumers and toward states. There might problems with this approach both in getting the numbers and in the fact that you might not be able to show that public consumption increased over the last 30 years to make up for some household consumption deficit.
ReplyDelete