29 November 2011

The crisis of neoliberalism in Europe (2)

Part 2 of 2 | Part 1
Despite the differences between the US and Europe in the average citizen’s experience of life, there have been some striking similarities in the development of deeper structures in the world’s two biggest economies since the advent of neoliberalism. This indicates that the crisis in Europe is not merely a result of “contamination” from the American credit crisis of 2008, as many Europeans initially argued. Yet neither is it a result of solely European problems of excessive spending or lagging competitiveness, as many Germans and Americans believe. It is, rather, a constituent part of the ongoing crisis of global neoliberalism.

It’s much harder to get a good grasp on these developments in Europe because aggregated statistics are not readily available before the advent of the eurozone and because exchange rates introduce some methodological problems, not to mention that the most important national economy used to be two different countries. This is further complicated by the UK’s decision to stay out of the single currency, leaving one of the key economies of Europe out of eurozone statistics. I’ve had no luck finding continuous time series that could give us the kind of elegant graphical picture of trends from Fordism to neoliberalism that we get for the US, so a more impressionistic jumble of charts for individual countries will have to suffice.

First, like the United States, growth in productivity has declined substantially from the rapid increases of the Fordist era (these charts are based on data from Eckhard Hein and Artur Tarassow, “Distribution, aggregate demand and productivity growth: theory and empirical results for six OECD countries based on a post-Kaleckian model”, Cambridge Journal of Economics (2010) 34, p. 728)





As can be seen, the collapse in productivity growth has been even more marked than that in the US, though the American (and British) numbers are padded by the tremendous amounts of fictitious capital its financial sector has generated since the mid-90s. As in the US, in order to maintain profit rates European corporations have captured a rising share of society’s production of value since the neoliberal rupture. The dotted lines below show the share of GDP taken by profits in A) Germany, B) France, C) Netherlands, D) Austria, E) UK, F) US; the straight lines show the evolution of productivity growth. Clearly, this development too has been more striking in Europe than the US (from Hein and Tarassow, p. 746):


At least in France, this has been accomplished by the same kind of wage suppression as in the US. Here we see that wages rose with productivity in the Fordist period and diverged sharply with the advent of neoliberalism (I was unable to locate similar data for other countries stretching back far enough, though the rising share of value going to capital indicates that this is a common phenomenon throughout Europe):
Source
Just as in the US, squeezing the enormous consumer market that had emerged under Fordism produced two significant problems: the prospect of mass unrest if living standards stagnated, and the question of how to actually sell the economy’s growing output if consumers’ incomes were not rising. And just as in the US, increasing levels of debt was the solution to both problems. But – and this is the basis of many of the observed differences in national life between the US and countries in Europe – the burden of this debt was taken up primarily by governments in Europe while individual borrowers were more important in the US (graph based on data supplied here):


In other words, broadly speaking, debt in Europe financed public goods that were equitably distributed (healthcare, public transit, welfare programs) while in the US it financed McMansions and SUVs. But in both cases, the issuance of this debt represented a claim on future production that could not be made good because productive outlets for investment in the economy were drying up.

We can see the sharp increase in government debts during the neoliberal period here:
Source
And, since that graph is a bit messy, here are individual ones for Italy:

Source
and France (the blue line is debt as a percentage of GDP):

Source
The rise of private debt in Europe, however, was also a significant development:

Source
Finally, just as in the US, the financial sector as a whole has become more and more important in the European economy:
Source
This graph overstates the significance of finance in the eurozone considered as a whole since French and German banks account for more of the sector than those of the other major economies, but the trend is clear. And with the exception of Greece and Italy, the speculative bubbles (mainly in real estate) that the European banks inflated in the UK, Spain, Ireland, and Iceland have been central to the seemingly national crises that have unfolded one after the other.

It goes without saying that there are many differences between the US and Europe that complicate this basic picture considerably, and I hope that we will have a chance to explore these further. But what I want to argue is that in a very fundamental way, the two economies (and not just the economies, but the politics and culture as well) have developed in a similar direction because they both adopted neoliberal social forms in response to the crisis of the 1970s.

It can hardly be denied that the American version of neoliberal social forms was far more extreme, marking a much sharper break with Fordist social forms than in Europe (with the exception of the UK). The partial survival of Fordist forms in Europe, including stronger unions, a more robust sense of the public good, and a less complete exposure of people to market insecurity, goes a long way toward explaining why life in Europe has been so much less savage there over the last three decades. It also accounts for Europe’s consistently slower rate of growth. These social forms were well adapted to the Fordist moment, but they were less successful – at least in capitalist terms – under neoliberal conditions.

Even so, precisely because neoliberalism was implemented in an extreme fashion in the US, the dysfunctions of the system were most pronounced there, and it was there that the crisis of neoliberalism exploded. Yet Europe, as a part of the unitary global order of neoliberalism, was not immune. And because its underlying model of growth was the same as in the US – consistent investment levels maintained only through corporations taking a rising share of value, with the problem of realizing value being solved through increasing debt – the crisis paralyzed prospects for future growth.

This crisis of growth has now assumed the form of a crisis in government finances because of the peculiar monetary system that mediates the euro. But the basic economic structures of neoliberalism remain in place, and the ideologies generated by the neoliberal era continue to block any initiatives but those that will deepen the crisis. It’s too soon to tell if the crisis in Europe will finally undo the short-term fixes that have forestalled complete global economic collapse. But even if the German government and ECB finally decide to save the currency before it’s too late, the crisis of growth will continue.

1 comment:

  1. This is very helpful. I'd like to see you go further on the idea that the continental model of neoliberalism relied on sovereign debt as opposed to consumer debt. I wonder if there's a way to quantify consumption in such a way to show more clearly that the increase in debt was causally linked to lagging demand. You might be able to use import/export numbers combined with gross output numbers to quantify consumption to show an increase in or at least constant aggregate consumption while the proportion of spending moved toward debt or away from individual consumers and toward states. There might problems with this approach both in getting the numbers and in the fact that you might not be able to show that public consumption increased over the last 30 years to make up for some household consumption deficit.

    ReplyDelete